Kantorovich Dual Problem (for general costs): Difference between revisions
Jump to navigation
Jump to search
Line 10: | Line 10: | ||
<math> I[\pi]= \int_{X\times Y} c(x,y) d\pi(x,y), \quad J(\varphi,\psi)=\int_{X}\varphi(x)d\mu(x)+\int_{Y}\psi(y) d\nu(y) </math>. | <math> I[\pi]= \int_{X\times Y} c(x,y) d\pi(x,y), \quad J(\varphi,\psi)=\int_{X}\varphi(x)d\mu(x)+\int_{Y}\psi(y) d\nu(y) </math>. | ||
Define <math> \Pi(\mu,\nu) </math> to be the set of Borel probability measures <math> \pi </math> on <math> X\times Y </math> such that for all measurable sets <math> A \subset X </math> and <math> B \subset Y </math>, <math> \pi[A\times Y]=\mu(A) </math>, <math> \pi[X\times B]=\nu(B) </math>, and define <math> \Phi_{c} </math> to be the set of all measurable functions <math> (\varphi, \psi) \in L^{1}(d\mu) \times L^{1}(d\nu) </math> satisfying <math> \varphi(x)+\psi(y) \leq c(x,y) </math> for <math> d\mu </math> almost everywhere in X and <math> d\nu </math> almost everywhere in Y. | Define <math> \Pi(\mu,\nu) </math> to be the set of Borel probability measures <math> \pi </math> on <math> X\times Y </math> such that for all measurable sets <math> A \subset X </math> and <math> B \subset Y </math>, <math> \pi[A\times Y]=\mu(A) </math>, <math> \pi[X\times B]=\nu(B) </math>, and define <math> \Phi_{c} </math> to be the set of all measurable functions <math> (\varphi, \psi) \in L^{1}(d\mu) \times L^{1}(d\nu) </math> satisfying <math> \varphi(x)+\psi(y) \leq c(x,y) </math> for <math> d\mu </math> almost everywhere in X and <math> d\nu </math> almost everywhere in Y. Then <math> inf_{\Pi(\mu,\nu)} I[\pi] = sup_{\Phi_{c}} J(\varphi,\psi) </math> | ||
==Proof of Theorem== | ==Proof of Theorem== |
Revision as of 23:06, 16 May 2020
Introduction
The main advantage of Kantorovich Problem, in comparison to Monge problem, is in the convex constraint property. It is possible to formulate the dual problem.
Statement of Theorem
(Kantorovich Duality) Let X and Y be Polish spaces, let and , and let a cost function be lower semi-continuous. Whenever and , define \newline .
Define to be the set of Borel probability measures on such that for all measurable sets and , , , and define to be the set of all measurable functions satisfying for almost everywhere in X and almost everywhere in Y. Then
Proof of Theorem
References
</ references>
- ↑ C. Villani, Topics in Optimal Transportation, Chapter 1. (pages 17-21)
- ↑ https://link-springer-com.proxy.library.ucsb.edu:9443/book/10.1007/978-3-319-20828-2 F. Santambrogio, Optimal Transport for Applied Mathematicians, Chapter 1.] (pages 9-16)